Friday, December 3, 2010

The Impact of the Stimulus Bill on the Labor Market: Does It Work, or Doesn’t It?

The Impact of the Stimulus Bill on the Labor Market:
Does It Work, or Doesn’t It?

         The rallying cry of “Buy American!” can be heard pervasively across the nation, stirring nationalist sentiments as America trudges along the path of economic recovery from the worst recession since the Great Depression. One of the most sharply divided debates in public policy is the one about the stimulus bill implemented in February 2009 called The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act.
         The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act’s controversial Buy American provision stipulates that if a project is on a public work, then all the iron and steel used in the project must be produced domestically. This provision aims to preserve or create at least three million manufacturing jobs for Americans. Will this policy retain jobs for Americans and spur economic growth, or will it ultimately diminish the welfare of the nation? In the short run, protectionism indeed preserves jobs for protected industries. However, as indicated by the 19th-century French economist Frédéric Bastiat, protection through free-trade restriction is an economic fallacy; in the long run it will slow down economic progress and represents a sheer loss to society.
         Frédéric Bastiat, in his influential commentary on economic sophisms “What is Seen and What is Not Seen,” reveals the fallacies contained in the argument for protectionism as a method of stimulating economic growth. Without limitations on trade, consumers can enjoy lower prices for the goods they consume. His essay outlines the argument of “Mr. Protectionist,” who asserts that by eliminating foreign competition, domestic firms can profit more through higher prices.  When firms charge higher prices, they help stimulate the economy by employing more workers and other resources. In turn, the incomes of resources owners will increase, and they will then consume more, thus fostering economic activity across the nation.
         Though Mr. Protectionist’s arguments are not false, they fail to account for economic consequences not immediately visible, as is the case with supporters of the stimulus plan. Bastiat reasoned that a law restraining free trade involves three key players. The first two are directly involved in the transactions as the buyer and seller. They are seen. The third could have been involved as the seller of whatever goods or services the consumer would have purchased from had it not been for the trade restriction; this third figure is not seen. At same time, this third player could have had more money to spend had it not been for the protectionist policy.
         Supporters of the stimulus plan may wonder, “How is it possible for anyone to have more spending power when jobs are being ‘outsourced?’”
         The consumers who would have paid less for building materials could have spent the money they saved elsewhere. Additionally, they could have purchased something else and gained enjoyment from the consumption of what they purchased. However, restrictions such as the Buy American provision result in consumers losing the value of whatever goods they could have purchased when free trade and competition resulted in lower prices before the protectionist policy. The double loss of the consumers offsets the gains made by the manufacturers and sellers of steel and iron.
         In applying Bastiat’s central theme to the Buy American provision of the stimulus plan, the three million jobs created or saved in the United States’ manufacturing industry are undeniable; because steel and iron cannot be obtained from abroad for public construction, they must be produced domestically, which means manufacturing jobs for Americans. This is seen.
         The not seen are the jobs that would have been created in other industries, as well as the enjoyment that would have been obtained from the consumption of the goods and services provided by non-Americans.  Frédéric Bastiat’s concept of unseen consequences does not simply exist in theory. For example, in the 1930’s the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act imposed taxes on over 20, 000 imported goods, which distorted and limited free trade. Economists now widely believe that this tariff greatly exacerbated the severity of the Great Depression.
         To echo the sentiments of Harvard economist Dr. Nicholas Gregory Mankiw in his 2009 New York Times article, this is no time for protectionism. Both the arguments presented by Frédéric Bastiat and lessons learned from public policy history demonstrate that protectionist policies lower the overall economic well-being of the nation and serve only to impede economic growth. The Buy American provision is therefore counterproductive; it defies economic wisdom and undermines the very economy it seeks to help recover.

McDonald's is the same all over the world! Or is it?

Interestingly enough, I just found out that an article I wrote a few years back is featured on both findarticles.com and allbusiness.com

Findarticles link: McDonald's in China

allbusiness link: McDonald's in China

The Buffalo News link: McDonald's in China

Work in sweatshops? No sweat!

To westerners and other citizens of industrialized nations, the conditions in sweatshops are horrid. How can we, as compassionate human beings, sit back and enjoy our flat-screen TV's, high-end cars, and gigantic houses, when young children no older than 14 spend 12 hours a day, 6 days a week toiling away in working conditions we wouldn't wish upon our worst enemies? I mean, these kids are denied bathroom breaks, exposed to dangerous chemicals, and subjected to numerous safety hazards. Any factory in the United States that did this would be immediately shut down.

But these sweatshops are not in the United States, Canada, England, Germany, or other high-income economies. Would these children work in such heart-wrenching conditions if they had better options? Put simply, no they wouldn't.

In outrage, Americans often enact policies that punish firms profiting off the cheap labor of sweatshops. However, ask any family whose children are working in a sweatshop, and they would be aghast at the thought of people purchasing less from these sweatshops.

Princeton economist Paul Krugman offers a [true] grisly tale about the effects of limiting imports from sweatshops:
"[Could] anything be worse than having children work in sweatshops? Alas, yes. In 1993, child workers in Bangladesh were found to be producing clothing for Wal-Mart, and Senator Tom Harkin proposed legislation banning imports from countries employing underage workers. The direct result was that Bangladeshi textile factories stopped employing children. But did the children go back to school? Did they return to happy homes? Not according to Oxfam, which found that the displaced child workers ended up in even worse jobs, or on the streets -- and that a significant number were forced into prostitution."
 (The full New York Times article can be found by clicking here.)


If the road to hell is paved with good intentions, surely any such legislation such as the import ban mentioned above is a guaranteed path to eternal doom.


On the contrary, sweatshops are the path out of economic bust for most lesser-developed countries. As stated by Nicholas Kristof and Sheryl Wudunn, "The simplest way to help the poorest Asians would be to buy more from sweatshops, not less."
"Read the article at: Two Cheers for Sweatshops."

According to a 2006 article in The Economist magazine, "No matter how awful we might consider the sweatshops of the developing world, if hundreds of people are queuing to get those jobs, it is obvious that whatever the alternatives are must be worse.   For many people in poor countries, factory jobs replace things like subsistence farming or prostitution; it would be no kindness to them to insist on wages or working conditions that would price their labour out of the global marketplace.  And as countries get richer, thanks to the gains from trade, they generally do adopt stricter labour regulations and more environmentally friendly practices."


Click here to read the full article. 


For a more in-depth analysis of the benefits sweatshops provide, read Chapter 12 of Charles Wheelan's Naked Economics,  Trade and Globalization.

Friday, November 5, 2010

A youtube video...

This is a video on youtube, directed by George Mason University's Russell Roberts. It details the conflicting economic philosophies of famed economists Friedrich Hayek and John Maynard Keynes, but in rap form!
We think you'll enjoy it:
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=d0nERTFo-Sk

Happy viewing!
-MaroonEcon

EDIT:
Here's another one:
http://www.educationalrap.com/music-contents/Demand_Supply-m764_p816.html

Why should I give a sh** about economics?

Hey everyone!
     So this is our first post. Before we explore other topics of interest more in depth, we thought we should shed light on the relevance and practicality of having economics knowledge. Economics is not the "dismal science," but takes part every day in our lives.
     Imagine this: it's a hot summer's day, and you're outside. You have plenty of liquid asset on you (liquid asset=cash), but the nearest grocery store to buy a drink from is a mile away, and you're on foot. Looks like you'll probably dehydrate before you even turn the street corner...
     But wait! Could it be??? Out of the corner of your eye, you glimpse a young entrepreneur. Yes, it is an elementary school student selling lemonade! Your dehydration problems are solved!
     "How much for a cup of lemonade?", you inquire of the future economist.
    "Just 25 cents," he responds.
     You open up your wallet, remove a quarter, and hand it to the boy. In exchange, he hands you a delicious cup of homemade lemonade. This transaction maximizes utility (utility=satisfaction derived from consumption) for both of you: you get to quench your thirst, the budding entrepreneur makes a profit. You value the lemonade more than the quarter, and the young lemonade salesman values the quarter more than his cup of lemonade. Mmmmmm delicious.
     This is not a hypothetical scenario-it's probably not hard to believe that I actually had this experience, as I am sure many of you out there have as well.
     Right as I was about to leave, the kid informed me that "refills are fifteen cents." When I heard this statement, I chuckled sheepishly to myself. This is the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility in action, demonstrated by  a child who is half my age!
    Economists like to think in marginal turns, which is, we like to think of the costs and benefits associated with each additional unit consumed. Perhaps I wasn't thirsty enough to pay another whole quarter for a cup of lemonade, but when the price was lowered, I found that the benefit, or enjoyment, I get from that new cup of lemonade exceeds the price I had to pay.
     Economics does not just apply to lemonade. Pretty much any decision you make, whether to eat another hamburger at McDonald's, whether to take an additional class this term in college, or whether or not to buy a new car, involves the analysis of the cost you have to pay, and the benefit you receive. It should be noted that cost is not always monetary-something that is "free" could take up a lot of your time, which you could have used to do something else.
     So now you see how economics has applications in even the most trivial of daily occurences. Hopefully you found it somewhat enlightening, or at the at least interesting. In future posts, we will continue to explore more intriguing topics.
-Kelly Tian